New Times,
New Thinking.

  1. Politics
  2. The Staggers
2 May 2018updated 06 Sep 2021 10:22am

Spring Statement 2018: why we should get rid of income tax bands

The basic rate can go too. 

By Alfie Stirling

This time last year, the Chancellor, Phillip Hammond, was preparing seemingly dry reforms to national insurance contributions (NICs) for his Spring Budget. Within days of being announced, the policies had become so politically charged they allegedly almost lost the Chancellor his job – and they were later mainly abandoned.

One year on, the Spring Statement may have changed its name, but Hammond remains at the Treasury’s helm and income taxes are still never far from the news headlines.

That’s not surprising. Employee national insurance and income tax combined make up nearly 12 per cent of GDP, absorb 13 per cent of gross household incomes and account for 34 per cent of total government tax receipts.

But our income taxes perform poorly against the most basic of tests. The UK’s tax system as a whole is regressive, when measured against family incomes in any given year. On average, the poorest 20 per cent of households pay 35 per cent of their gross income in tax, more than the average for all other households.

Income taxes should be the main tool to improve this picture, but in fact, the government’s current plans are set to make things worse.

The Conservative manifesto proposed lifting the personal allowance and higher rate threshold of income tax. This would mean post-tax incomes for the richest 10 per cent of families rising five times faster than for the poorest 10 per cent.

The current system of allowances, rates and tax bands leads to perverse economic incentives. If you earn more than £11,500 from work, you pay 32 per cent of this in tax after both income tax and employee national insurance are deducted. 

Give a gift subscription to the New Statesman this Christmas from just £49

But at the same time, if you earn dividends from money you have invested, these earnings are charged at 7.5 per cent. For those on Universal Credit, the combined effect of tax and benefit withdrawal means some people keep just 25p from an increase in pay of £1.

The design and complexity of our income tax system also makes raising revenue politically difficult. Any change creates groups of “losers” – whether actual or perceived – from most tax-raising proposals. This is precisely what the Chancellor discovered last year with his NICs plans.

These failings are structural in nature, and simply tinkering with rates and allowances within the current system will not lead to significant improvements. If income taxes are going to better meet their goals, their very structure needs to change.

That’s why the Institute for Public Policy Research has today published a policy report for the Commission on Economic Justice that proposes to do precisely that.

Our major reform has two elements.

First, all rates and allowance within income tax and employee NICs would be combined into a single schedule of tax rates. This means that different sources of income would be taxed at the same rate, and on the same terms. Income tax and employee NICs would no longer exist as separate taxes, but contributions to national insurance through the new income tax could continue on a similar basis as today, and could remain itemised on individual’s payslips. [WHY IS THIS IMPORTANT?]

Second, the existing system of marginal tax bands (better known as the basic rate, higher rate and additional rate of tax) would be replaced by a formula. Your marginal tax rate would depend on your own precise level of income.

In effect, the current system of rates and bands would be replaced by a smooth and gradual increase in marginal tax rates as an individual’s income rises, starting from a tax free allowance at the bottom and a maximum rate of tax at the top. This would be similar to how Germany already manages part of its income tax system today.

Our illustrative modelling shows how such a system could reduce tax rates the most for the very lowest earners, increase financial work incentives for those on Universal Credit by up to 40 per cent, and increase annual take-home for those on middle incomes by around £1,100.

In fact, such reforms have the potential to receive political support from a wide spectrum of taxpayers. Our results show that moving to such a system could give money back to 84 per cent of taxpayers without costing government a penny, while raising taxes for the very richest by an average of less than 3 percentage points.

The new system would also make it much easier politically to raise income taxes to pay for public services. For example, all of the money needed to plug the annual NHS funding gap expected by 2020/21 could be found by an overall tax change, which still gave small reductions in tax to 75 per cent of taxpayers.

Having been burned once, it’s unlikely that the present Chancellor will try his hand again at reforming income taxes sometime soon. But for a government of any colour wishing to take seriously the challenges presented by a tired, outdated and underperforming tax system, such proposals might just provide part of the answer.

Alfie Stirling is a Senior Economic Analyst at IPPR and author of ‘Tapering Over The Tax’. Follow him @alfie_stirling.

Content from our partners
Building Britain’s water security
How to solve the teaching crisis
Pitching in to support grassroots football